CLAUDIA WILKEN, District Judge.
Defendant Abbott Laboratories moves for summary judgment or, alternatively, summary adjudication on the claims of Direct Purchaser Plaintiffs Safeway, Inc., et al.; Meijer, Inc., et al.; and Rite Aid Corporation, et al. (collectively, Direct Purchasers) and for summary judgment on Plaintiff GlaxoSmithKline's (GSK) claims. Direct Purchasers and GSK oppose Abbott's motions. The motions were heard on October 28, 2010. Having considered oral argument and the papers submitted by the parties, the Court GRANTS Abbott's motions in part and DENIES them in part.
Protease inhibitors (Pls) are considered the most potent class of drugs to combat the HIV virus. In 1996, Abbott introduced Norvir as a stand-alone PI with a daily
After Norvir's release, it was discovered that, when used in small quantities with another PI, Norvir would "boost" the antiviral properties of that PI. Not only did a small dose of Norvir—about 100 to 400 milligrams per day—make other PIs more effective and decrease the side effects associated with high doses, but it also slowed the rate at which HIV developed resistance to the effects of those PIs. The use of Norvir as a "booster" has enabled HIV patients to live longer. But the use of Norvir as a booster, and not a stand-alone PI, has also meant that the price for an average daily dose of Norvir has plummeted since Norvir was first introduced, because patients need a much smaller daily dose of Norvir when it is used as a booster compared to when it is used as a standalone PI. By 2003, the average price for a daily dose of Norvir was $1.71.
In 2000, Abbott introduced Kaletra, a single "soft gel capsule" containing the PI lopinavir as well as ritonavir, used to boost the effects of lopinavir. Calamari Decl. ¶ 15. A single capsule contained 133 milligrams of lopinavir and 33 milligrams of ritanovir.
In 2003, two new PIs, Bristol-Myers Squibb's Reyataz and GSK's Lexiva, were introduced to the market. Although both drugs could be prescribed as stand-alone PIs, their daily doses were less if they were administered along with Norvir. A daily dose of Reyataz, unboosted by Norvir, was 400 milligrams; if boosted by 100 milligrams of Norvir, Reyataz's daily dose was 300 milligrams. A daily, unboosted dose of Lexiva was 2,800 milligrams; if taken with 100 or 200 milligrams of Norvir, Lexiva's daily dose was 1,400 milligrams. Abbott was aware of studies that showed Norvir-boosted doses of Reyataz and Lexiva had efficacy similar to Kaletra and, in several ways, were superior to Kaletra. See Stockinger Decl., Ex. 98, at NOR00096554-55. Without a boosting dose of Norvir, however, these drugs were inferior to Kaletra.
After the introduction of Reyataz, Kaletra's market share fell. The average daily dose of Norvir also fell. Before Reyataz's release, the most common boosting dose of Norvir ranged from 200 milligrams to 400 milligrams a day. Clinical trials, however, showed that a Norvir dose of only 100 milligrams a day effectively boosted Reyataz.
By September, 2003, Abbott was aware that Reyataz and Lexiva would threaten Kaletra's future market share and cause it to lose revenue. Abbott considered three options to preserve its "HIV leadership in the PI class": (1) continue to execute licensing agreements with competitors for the co-marketing of their PIs along with Norvir, similar to the one Abbott and GSK agreed to in December, 2002, see generally Calamari Decl., Ex. 23 at NOR0004414; (2) remove Norvir from the market; or (3) increase the price of Norvir. See Stockinger Decl., Ex. 17 at RIT0437434. Abbott concluded that the first would not be sufficient to stem projected revenue losses and that the second would cause "significant issues . . . on PR and regulatory fronts both domestically and internationally." Id. Abbott's staff ultimately decided to recommend an increase in the price of Norvir. See Stockinger Decl., Ex. 95, at NOR00091874. Abbott CEO Miles White approved the increase in late October, 2003.
On December 3, 2003, Abbott raised the price of 100 milligrams of Norvir from $1.71 to $8.57, which amounted to a 400-percent increase. In contrast, Abbott's four previous price increases averaged 3.45
Since December, 2003, Norvir's price has remained at $8.57 per 100 milligrams, whereas the prices for boosted PIs have risen. In December, 2003, the price of a daily dose of Kaletra was $18.78. After slightly reducing Kaletra's price to $18.76 in 2004, through four price hikes between June, 2005 and December, 2007, Abbott increased Kaletra's price to $23.40, a rise of approximately twenty-five percent. Between June, 2005 and December, 2007, the cost of a daily dose of Reyataz, not including Norvir, increased approximately eleven percent, from $23.14 to $25.76. And the cost for a daily dose of Lexiva, not including Norvir, increased approximately twenty-two percent over the same period, from $16.78 to $20.40. See Calamari Decl. ¶¶ 45-46, tbl.1.
At the time of the Norvir price increase, Kaletra commanded a substantial share of the boosted PI market. Since then, its share has declined. In comparison, the market shares of Reyataz and Lexiva have increased, along with that of Prezista, a boosted PI introduced in June, 2006.
Direct Purchasers allege that, in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, Abbott monopolized or attempted to monopolize the "boosted market," which Plaintiffs define to be the market in which Kaletra competes with Reyataz, Lexiva and other PIs boosted by Norvir. Specifically, Direct Purchasers complain that Abbott set predatory prices for Kaletra, which they argue is a bundled product, and violated its antitrust duty to deal with respect to Norvir. Direct Purchasers also allege that Abbott monopolized the "boosting market," which Plaintiffs define to be a market in which Norvir is the only product. In the Meijer action, the Court has certified a class of:
Order of August 27, 2008 at 21, Meijer v. Abbott Laboratories, Case No. 07-5985 CW, 2008 WL 4065839.
GSK also alleges that Abbott monopolized or attempted to monopolize the boosted market, in violation of Section 2. Specifically, GSK claims that Abbott violated its antitrust duty to deal with respect to Norvir and sabotaged its competitors. In addition, GSK brings claims under New York law for breach of the implied covenant of good faith and fair dealing related to its co-marketing licensing agreement with Abbott. Finally, GSK pleads claims for violations of North Carolina's Unfair and Deceptive Trade Practices Act (UDTPA), N.C. Gen.Stat. §§ 75-1.1, et seq. The UDTPA, among other things, prohibits monopolization and attempted monopolization. Id. § 75-2.1.
The current cases are related to John Doe 1 v. Abbott Laboratories, No. C 04-1511 CW. Although that case also concerned the December, 2003 increase in Norvir's price, the Doe plaintiffs based their Section 2 claim on a theory of monopoly leveraging. See John Doe 1 v. Abbott Laboratories, 571 F.3d 930, 933 (9th Cir. 2009). The Ninth Circuit held that the plaintiffs' stand-alone monopoly leveraging claim was foreclosed by Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. Linkline Communications, Inc., 555 U.S. 438, 129 S.Ct. 1109, 172 L.Ed.2d 836 (2009). The Ninth Circuit noted that the Doe plaintiffs did not allege predatory pricing or a refusal to deal. Doe, 571 F.3d at 935. Allegations of such conduct are plead here.
In its motion to dismiss, Abbott argued that the Ninth Circuit's decision in Doe controlled the outcome of this case and foreclosed relief on Plaintiffs' claims. The Court denied Abbott's motion, concluding that Doe was distinguishable because Plaintiffs here alleged predatory pricing and a refusal to deal. Abbott then filed a motion to certify issues for interlocutory appeal, which the Court denied. Thereafter, Abbott petitioned the Ninth Circuit for a writ of mandamus, seeking enforcement of its mandate in Doe. The Ninth Circuit denied Abbott's petition on September 28, 2010.
In a footnote in its opposition to Abbott's motion for summary judgment, GSK asserted that the motion did not address two theories of antitrust liability it had raised in opposition to Abbott's motion to dismiss: (1) under the circumstances of this case, it could still sue under Section 2 on a "monopoly leveraging plus" theory, notwithstanding Linkline and the Ninth Circuit's decision in Doe; and (2) Abbott's conduct was analogous to the tortious acts held to violate Section 2 in Conwood Co., L.P. v. U.S. Tobacco Co., 290 F.3d 768 (6th Cir.2002). GSK also asserted in the footnote that, if Direct Purchasers survived summary judgment on their predatory pricing claim under Cascade Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, 515 F.3d 883 (9th Cir.2008), it should also be entitled to go to trial on its "equally efficient competitor test." GSK Opp'n 18 n. 18. At the October 28, 2010 hearing on Abbott's motions, the Court allowed further briefing from GSK and Abbott regarding the assertions in GSK's footnote.
Summary judgment is properly granted when no genuine and disputed issues of material fact remain, and when, viewing the evidence most favorably to the non-moving party, the movant is clearly entitled to prevail as a matter of law. Fed. R.Civ.P. 56; Celotex Corp. v. Catrett, 477 U.S. 317, 322-23, 106 S.Ct. 2548, 91 L.Ed.2d 265 (1986); Eisenberg v. Ins. Co. of N. Am., 815 F.2d 1285, 1288-89 (9th Cir.1987).
Material facts which would preclude entry of summary judgment are those which, under applicable substantive law, may affect the outcome of the case. The substantive law will identify which facts are material. Anderson v. Liberty Lobby, Inc., 477 U.S. 242, 248, 106 S.Ct. 2505, 91 L.Ed.2d 202 (1986).
Where the moving party does not bear the burden of proof on an issue at trial, the moving party may discharge its burden of production by either of two methods:
Nissan Fire & Marine Ins. Co., Ltd., v. Fritz Cos., Inc., 210 F.3d 1099, 1106 (9th Cir.2000).
If the moving party discharges its burden by showing an absence of evidence to support an essential element of a claim or defense, it is not required to produce evidence showing the absence of a material fact on such issues, or to support its motion with evidence negating the non-moving party's claim. Id.; see also Lujan v. Nat'l Wildlife Fed'n, 497 U.S. 871, 885, 110 S.Ct. 3177, 111 L.Ed.2d 695 (1990); Bhan v. NME Hosps., Inc., 929 F.2d 1404, 1409 (9th Cir.1991). If the moving party shows an absence of evidence to support the non-moving party's case, the burden then shifts to the non-moving party to produce "specific evidence, through affidavits or admissible discovery material, to show that the dispute exists." Bhan, 929 F.2d at 1409.
If the moving party discharges its burden by negating an essential element of the non-moving party's claim or defense, it must produce affirmative evidence of such negation. Nissan, 210 F.3d at 1105. If the moving party produces such evidence, the burden then shifts to the non-moving party to produce specific evidence to show that a dispute of material fact exists. Id.
If the moving party does not meet its initial burden of production by either method, the non-moving party is under no obligation to offer any evidence in support of its opposition. Id. This is true even though the non-moving party bears the ultimate burden of persuasion at trial. Id. at 1107.
Section 2 of the Sherman Act "makes it unlawful to monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, . . . any part of the trade or commerce among the several States." Linkline, 129 S.Ct. at 1118. To establish liability for a monopolization claim, a plaintiff must demonstrate "(1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and (2) the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished
Abbott asserts that Plaintiffs' claims for monopolization and attempted monopolization fail because they have not demonstrated (1) its possession of monopoly power in the boosted market or (2) anticompetitive conduct. Abbott also maintains that Direct Purchasers did not suffer antitrust injury.
Monopoly power is "`the power to control prices or exclude competition.'"
With respect to direct evidence, Plaintiffs cite this Court's decision in Doe, in which the Court concluded that sufficient direct evidence created a triable issue with respect to Abbott's monopoly power. Like the Doe plaintiffs, Plaintiffs here point to evidence that the 400-percent increase in Norvir's price impacted the boosted market. Dr. Leffler, Plaintiffs' expert, opined that Abbott's control over Norvir, which was a necessary "input" for boosted PIs, gave it control over the boosted market. Stockinger Decl., Ex. 70 ¶ 32. Further, there is evidence that Abbott was aware that raising Norvir's price would affect the boosted market, and that GSK believed that Lexiva's sales performance was negatively impacted by the price hike. See Stockinger Decl., Ex. 95, at NOR00091874 and Ex. 118 ¶ 9. The Ninth Circuit has stated, "Direct proof of market power may be shown by evidence of restricted output and supracompetitive prices." Forsyth, 114 F.3d at 1475. There is no rule, however, that this is the only way monopoly power can be proved.
Plaintiffs contend that they have amassed additional direct evidence. They argue that Abbott's pricing of Kaletra above its average marginal cost demonstrated its monopoly power. However, Plaintiffs do not offer evidence that pricing above average marginal cost was necessarily supracompetitive, particularly in the pharmaceutical industry. Indeed, Dr. Leffler opined that Kaletra, Reyataz and Lexiva are all priced "substantially above" average marginal cost. Senator Decl., Ex. B at 191:1-21. That all boosted market participants priced above average marginal cost precludes any inference that such pricing reflected Abbott's monopoly power.
Further, supracompetitive pricing, on its own, is not direct evidence of monopoly power. See Forsyth, 114 F.3d at 1476; see also Harrison Aire, Inc. v. Aerostar Int'l, Inc., 423 F.3d 374, 381 (3d Cir.2005); Geneva Pharmas. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Laboratories Inc., 386 F.3d 485, 500 (2d Cir.2004); Blue Cross & Blue Shield United of Wis. v. Marshfield Clinic, 65 F.3d 1406, 1412 (7th Cir.1995). To prove monopoly power directly, supracompetitive pricing must be accompanied by restricted output. Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1434. Both are required to prove monopoly power directly.
Plaintiffs argue that they offer evidence of restricted output, albeit indirectly. They do not claim that output in the boosted market decreased following the December, 2003 Norvir price increase; indeed, undisputed evidence shows the contrary. Instead, Plaintiffs maintain that, but for the price hike, output would have been greater. They point to Dr. Leffler's opinion that, had Abbott not increased Norvir's price, its sales of Norvir "would have been substantially higher." Stockinger Decl., Ex. 103 ¶ 58. From this, Plaintiffs argue that sales in the boosted market also would have necessarily been higher, in that a sale of Norvir would ordinarily entail a sale of a boosted PI because Norvir is no longer prescribed as a stand-alone PI. However, Dr. Leffler did not address this point and the discussion to which Plaintiffs refer did not concern the boosted market.
Accordingly, Plaintiffs provide direct evidence of Abbott's monopoly power
To prove monopoly power circumstantially, "a plaintiff must: (1) define the relevant market, (2) show that the defendant owns a dominant share of that market, and (3) show that there are significant barriers to entry and show that existing competitors lack the capacity to increase their output in the short run." Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1434. In addition to providing direct evidence, Plaintiffs offer circumstantial evidence of Abbott's monopoly power.
"A relevant market, for antitrust purposes, can be broadly characterized in terms of the cross-elasticity of demand for or reasonable interchangeability of a given set of products or services." Coal. for ICANN Transparency, Inc. v. Verisign, Inc., 611 F.3d 495, 507 (9th Cir. 2010) (citations and internal quotation marks omitted). Courts "consider whether the product and its substitutes are reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purpose, as well as industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate economic entity, the product's peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors." Id. (citations omitted).
As noted above, Plaintiffs maintain that the relevant market is the boosted market, and that this includes Reyataz, Lexiva and Kaletra and other PIs that require Norvir as a booster. Plaintiffs present evidence of Abbott's internal documents, which, according to Plaintiffs' expert Dr. Singer, indicate that it believed that Reyataz, Lexiva and Kaletra were all in the same market and impacted each other's prices. Further, Abbott's economics expert, Dr. Lagenfeld, acknowledged at his deposition that Kaletra's price would impact its market share relative to its "boosted PI rivals." Stockinger Decl., Ex. 114, at 32:8-23. This is sufficient to create a question of fact on the definition of a boosted market.
Abbott challenges Plaintiffs' definition as overly narrow, pointing to Plaintiffs' medical experts' testimony that non-nucleoside reverse transcriptase inhibitors (NNRTIs) are functionally comparable to boosted PIs. See, e.g., Calamari Decl., Ex. 2, at 145:1-148:11. However, this similarity does not preclude Plaintiffs' definition of the boosted market for antitrust purposes. These experts' testimony suggests that there are several HIV therapies, including NNRTIs and boosted PIs. The testimony is not inconsistent with Plaintiffs' definition of a boosted PI submarket that exists within a broader HIV therapy market. "A submarket exists if it is sufficiently insulated from the larger market so that supply and demand are inelastic with the larger market." Forsyth, 114 F.3d at 1476 (citation and internal quotation marks omitted). Indeed, Plaintiffs offer evidence that the Norvir-driven price increases of boosted PI therapies did not cause a cognizable flight to NNRTIs or other alternative therapies.
Abbott also argues that Plaintiffs do not offer any econometric analyses of cross-elasticity. However, Dr. Singer testified at his deposition that he conducted a cross-elasticity analysis, stating that he "looked at changes in market shares around the time of the . . . Norvir price increase, which is a way to get at price cross-elasticity." Stockinger Decl., Ex. 106, at 262:7-11. Abbott points to no requirement that such an analysis must be statistical in nature.
"A mere showing of substantial or even dominant market share alone cannot establish market power sufficient to carry out a predatory scheme." Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1439. Conversely, a "declining market share may reflect an absence of market power, but it does not foreclose a finding of such power." Oahu Gas Serv., Inc. v. Pac. Resources, Inc., 838 F.2d 360, 366 (9th Cir.1988) (citation omitted).
Abbott does not dispute that it commanded an overwhelming share of the boosted market in December, 2003, the time of the Norvir price increase. Nor does it dispute that Plaintiffs' experts show that, through the third quarter of 2007, it held a substantial share of the market. Instead, Abbott challenges the method by which Plaintiffs' experts measure its market share. This does not warrant summary judgment. Whether ritanovir, either sold through Norvir or in co-formulation with lopinavir in Kaletra, should be included in calculating Abbott's market share in the boosted market is a matter to be decided by a jury.
Accordingly, there is a genuine dispute for trial concerning whether Abbott owns a sufficiently dominant share of the boosted market.
"A high market share, though it may ordinarily raise an inference of monopoly power, will not do so in a market with low entry barriers or other evidence of a defendant's inability to control prices or exclude competitors." Oahu Gas, 838 F.2d at 366 (citing Grinnell, 384 U.S. at 571, 86 S.Ct. 1698). Barriers to entry include "(1) legal license requirements; (2) control of an essential or superior resource; (3) entrenched buyer preferences for established brands; (4) capital market evaluations imposing higher capital costs on new entrants; and, in some situations, (5) economies of scale." Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1439 (footnote omitted). The existence of entry barriers, however, is not sufficient to support an inference of market power. "The ability to control output and prices— the essence of market power—depends largely on the ability of existing firms to quickly increase their own output in response to a contraction by the defendant." Id. at 1441. Control over one market may be considered in determining whether a firm has control of another. See Pac. Coast Agric. Export Ass'n v. Sunkist Growers, Inc., 526 F.2d 1196, 1204 (9th Cir.1975).
Plaintiffs' experts opined that Abbott had monopoly power based on its high market share in a differentiated product market with high barriers to entry. Dr. Noll, Plaintiffs' expert, stated that this power existed from "2002 through at least the end of 2006." Stockinger Decl., Ex. 50, at 8. As Abbott acknowledges, to market entails high research and development regulatory approval, both of which constitute See Barr Labs. Inc., 386 F.3d at 499 (concluding that "regulatory requirements to sell" generic drugs were a barrier to entry). Further, Abbott does not dispute that it controls the supply of Norvir, which can be understood to be "an essential . . . resource" for the boosted market. Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1439. Its power over a necessary input posed barriers to entry and expansion: to limit either, Abbott could have increased the cost of Norvir, as it did, which could have rendered Kaletra's potential or existing competitors unattractive to consumers. Thus, there is a triable issue as to whether there were barriers to entry and expansion.
Abbott contends that the erosion of its market share between December, 2003
Abbott relies primarily on United States v. Syufy Enterprises, 903 F.2d 659 (9th Cir.1990). There, the court concluded that, although a firm had a large market share, its inability to maintain it demonstrated a lack of monopoly power. Id. at 666. The market in Syufy, however, had no substantial barriers to entry. 903 F.2d at 666-67 (contrasting circumstances there to cases involving industries that required "onerous front-end investments that might deter competition from all but the hardiest and most financially secure investors"). Abbott correctly notes that Syufy did not expressly limit its teachings to circumstances in which entry barriers are absent. However, as Oahu Gas indicates, declining market share is not necessarily sufficient to warrant summary judgment. See 838 F.2d at 366; see also Areeda and Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law, ¶ 801a2, at 385 ("[A] steadily declining share suggests that substantial power is transitory. . . . However, it is not in itself enough."). Although it may be that Abbott lacked monopoly power, this is for a jury to decide.
Accordingly, through both direct and circumstantial evidence, Plaintiffs create a triable issue of fact as to whether Abbott had monopoly power. Summary judgment is not warranted on the ground that Abbott lacked monopoly power.
As noted above, in addition to demonstrating monopoly power, Plaintiffs must provide evidence of anticompetitive conduct.
Four theories of anticompetitive conduct have been raised in this action: (1) predatory pricing through bundled-product discounting, which GSK terms the "equally efficient competitor test"; (2) a violation of Abbott's antitrust duty to deal; (3) a "monopoly leveraging plus" theory based on government-pricing rules in the boosting market; and (4) a business tort theory under Conwood. At the hearing on Abbott's motions, Direct Purchasers and GSK clarified that they seek Section 2 liability based on each of the four theories, even though they may not have raised them in their respective opposition briefs to Abbott's current motions and motions to dismiss. They maintain that their complaints offer sufficient allegations to put Abbott on notice of these theories.
Abbott argues that, to assert a predatory pricing theory of liability, GSK must amend its complaint.
First, Plaintiffs assert that Abbott acted anticompetitively by engaging in predatory pricing with respect to Kaletra, which they maintain is a bundled product containing lopinavir and ritanovir. In particular, Direct Purchasers maintain that, under Cascade's discount attribution rule, the imputed price of lopinavir, the competitive component of Kaletra, is below its average variable cost to produce and, therefore, predatory. Abbott maintains that Kaletra is not a bundled product and Cascade does not apply. Abbott does not challenge Dr. Singer's conclusion that, under the Cascade discount attribution rule, lopinavir's imputed price is below its average variable cost.
Direct Purchasers argue that Abbott should be held to its prior litigation position that Kaletra is a bundled product, either because its earlier statements constitute admissions of fact or because it should be estopped from asserting otherwise. This argument is unavailing. Abbott's earlier statements were not admissions of fact, but rather legal arguments. See In re Teleglobe Commc'ns Corp., 493 F.3d 345, 377 (3d Cir.2007) ("To be binding, admissions . . . must be statements of fact that require evidentiary proof, not statements of legal theories."); Am. Title Ins. Co. v. Lacelaw Corp., 861 F.2d 224, 227 (9th Cir.1988) (stating that trial courts have discretion to accept statements of fact as judicial admissions). Nor does judicial estoppel apply here. Although the "doctrine of judicial estoppel bars a party from taking inconsistent positions in the same litigation," it does not apply if "no court ever adopted the original . . . position." Masayesva ex rel. Hopi Indian Tribe v. Hale, 118 F.3d 1371, 1382 (9th Cir.1997); see also Hamilton v. State Farm Fire & Cas. Co., 270 F.3d 778, 782 (9th Cir.2001) (in determining whether judicial estoppel should apply, "courts regularly inquire whether the party has succeeded in persuading a court to accept that party's earlier position"). Because no court accepted Abbott's earlier legal arguments that Kaletra was a bundled product under Cascade, they do not judicially estop Abbott from taking a different legal position in light of Linkline and the Ninth Circuit's opinion in Doe. Here, Abbott maintains that Kaletra is a single, integrated product, "no more a bundle of its APIs [active pharmaceutical ingredients] than bread is a bundle of flour, milk, and salt." Mot. for Summ. J. on Direct Purchasers' Claims 19. It maintains that the Cascade court intended the discount attribution rule to be applied only to bundles comprised of "separate, independent products being packaged or sold together for a single price." Id. Direct Purchasers respond that their "economists have concluded that Kaletra is a bundle . . . because consumers would, could, and did assemble the bundle (boosted PI plus ritonavir) on their own." Direct Purchasers' Opp'n 20. In other words, Direct Purchasers maintain that bundles are comprised of products that consumers naturally would purchase together.
Abbott's arguments are not persuasive. Retail drugs and their APIs present special challenges with regard to bundling. Abbott explains in detail that APIs must be combined with "excipients, principally solvents and stabilizers, in a formulation designed to optimize factors including
Abbott's bread analogy is therefore inapt. Consumers do not purchase bread in order to obtain flour, milk and salt. Further, unlike the combination of flour, milk, salt and other ingredients to make bread, the combination of lopinavir and ritanovir does not create a product functionally different from its components. Bundled or separate, these two APIs remain PIs.
Accordingly, Kaletra can be regarded as a bundled product for the purposes of Cascade's discount attribution rule. As noted above, this was the only challenge Abbott raised with respect to Plaintiffs' predatory pricing theory of liability. Thus, Plaintiffs' monopolization and attempted monopolization claims are viable to the extent that they are based on this theory.
Plaintiffs' second theory is that Abbott acted anticompetitively by violating its antitrust duty to deal. Their theory rests on allegations that
Direct Purchasers' Opp'n 23. Abbott contends that there is no evidence that Norvir was priced at a level that its rivals or consumers "could not accept" or evidence that it unilaterally terminated a voluntary course of dealing with its rivals to set Norvir's price.
"As a general rule, businesses are free to choose the parties with whom they will deal, as well as the prices, terms, and conditions of that dealing." Linkline, 129 S.Ct. at 1118. However, there are "limited circumstances in which a firm's unilateral refusal to deal with its rivals can give rise to antitrust liability." Id. (citing Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 105 S.Ct. 2847, 86 L.Ed.2d 467 (1985)).
In Aspen Skiing, the Supreme Court upheld a jury verdict of Section 2 liability when a "monopolist elected to make an important change in a pattern of distribution that had originated in a competitive market and had persisted for several years." 472 U.S. at 603, 105 S.Ct. 2847. The defendant owned three of the four ski resorts in Aspen, Colorado. Id. at 587-89, 105 S.Ct. 2847. For several years, the defendant, along with the plaintiff who owned the fourth ski resort, had offered a ski lift pass that could be used at any Aspen ski resort. Id. at 589-90, 105 S.Ct. 2847. Proceeds from the sale of the all-Aspen pass were divided between the defendant and the plaintiff, based on a survey of which resorts consumers actually frequented. Id. at 590-91, 105 S.Ct. 2847. The plaintiff's share of revenue fluctuated year-to-year, depending on its attendance
On appeal, the defendant asserted that it had no duty to deal with the plaintiff. The Supreme Court agreed that, generally, a business has a right to select customers and associates, but stated that this right is not unqualified. Id. at 601, 105 S.Ct. 2847. Quoting Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143, 155, 72 S.Ct. 181, 96 L.Ed. 162 (1951), the Supreme Court stated,
Aspen Skiing, 472 U.S. at 602, 105 S.Ct. 2847 (emphasis supplied by Aspen Skiing court). Because it found sufficient evidence that anticompetitive intent motivated the defendant's unreasonable offer, the Court upheld the jury's verdict in favor of the plaintiff.
In Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 124 S.Ct. 872, 157 L.Ed.2d 823 (2004), the Supreme Court revisited Aspen Skiing. There, the plaintiff brought Section 2 claims, alleging that, under Aspen Skiing, Verizon violated an antitrust duty to deal when it failed to provide its rivals with timely access to its telecommunications network, for which Verizon had already been sanctioned by government agencies under the Telecommunications Act of 1996. Id. at 403-05, 124 S.Ct. 872. The Court rejected the plaintiff's claim. Although the Court reaffirmed the potential for liability under Aspen Skiing, it distinguished that case and reasoned that the Aspen Skiing Court "found significance" in two of the defendant's acts, both of which suggested anticompetitive motives: (1) the "unilateral termination of a voluntary (and thus presumably profitable) course of dealing" and (2) "the defendant's unwillingness to renew the ticket even if compensated at retail price." Trinko, 540 U.S. at 409, 124 S.Ct. 872 (emphasis in original). Unlike the Aspen Skiing plaintiff, Trinko did not allege that Verizon "voluntarily engaged in a course of dealing with its rivals, or would ever have done so absent statutory compulsion." Id. Thus, the Court reasoned, Verizon's "prior conduct sheds no light upon the motivation of its refusal to deal—upon whether its regulatory lapses were prompted not by competitive zeal but by anticompetitive malice." Id. The Court also noted that the Telecommunications Act of 1996 required Verizon to provide services not available to the public, which made the case "different from Aspen Skiing in a more fundamental way." Id. The Court explained,
Id. at 410, 124 S.Ct. 872 (citations omitted).
In MetroNet Services Corp. v. Qwest Corp., 383 F.3d 1124 (9th Cir.2004), the Ninth Circuit reconsidered, in light of Trinko, its prior reversal of a district court's grant of summary judgment in favor of an antitrust defendant. The court noted that Trinko identified three circumstances that were "significant for creating antitrust liability": (1) "the unilateral termination of a voluntary and profitable course of dealing;" (2) a refusal to deal or an "offer to deal with a competitor only on unreasonable terms and conditions," which could "amount to a practical refusal to deal;" and (3) a refusal to provide competitors with "products that were already sold in a retail market to other customers." MetroNet, 383 F.3d at 1132-34. Concluding that the plaintiffs' evidence did not contain these hallmarks, the court noted that their theory of liability did "not fit comfortably in the Aspen Skiing mold" and affirmed summary judgment in favor the defendant. Id. at 1132.
Here, in its motion to dismiss, Abbott argued, based on Trinko and MetroNet, that Plaintiffs' antitrust duty-to-deal claims did not fall within the scope of Aspen Skiing. The Court denied the motion, holding that liability under Section 2 could arise if a defendant unilaterally alters a voluntary course of dealing and "anticompetitive malice" motivates the defendant's conduct. See MetroNet, 383 F.3d at 1131-32. The Court noted Metro-Net's observation that Aspen Skiing could apply in cases involving a practical refusal to deal, in which a defendant offered its competitors only on unreasonable terms and conditions. In opposition to Abbott's motions for summary judgment, Plaintiffs provide evidence that creates a genuine issue of fact with respect to the three factors of significance identified in Metro-Net and the elements outlined by the Court in its order on Abbott's motions to dismiss.
Plaintiffs offer evidence that Abbott unilaterally terminated a voluntary course of dealing by increasing the price of Norvir approximately four hundred percent and did so at some expense. Plaintiffs offer undisputed evidence that, before December, 2003, Abbott's previous price increases were in line with the rate of inflation. Further, Dr. Noll opines that Norvir's 400-percent price increase in December, 2003 came at some cost, including a diminished rate of profit and a drop in Abbott's stock price. Abbott responds that Trinko found anticompetitive significance only in unilateral changes in "cooperative ventures" between competitors. But Trinko did not so hold. The Trinko Court noted that Aspen Skiing involved such a venture, but it was the unilateral termination of a voluntary and profitable course of dealing
Plaintiffs have likewise tendered evidence of a practical refusal to deal. For instance, Abbott does not dispute that the Norvir price hike made Kaletra's rival boosted PI therapies significantly more expensive. To illustrate, the Norvir price increase caused the cost of a therapy based on GSK's Lexiva to jump from $19.42 to $33.14. A jury could view this as an offer to deal only on unreasonable terms and conditions. Abbott argues that consumers' continued purchases of Norvir precludes, as a matter of law, a finding that its price was unreasonable. This argument is unavailing. Doctors might have continued to prescribe an unreasonably priced drug if it were necessary to the health or life of their patients.
Finally, a jury could infer that Abbott refused to provide its competitors with Norvir on the same terms that it provided the drug to its retail customers. As noted above, Norvir is the trade name for the API ritanovir. To avail themselves of the benefits of ritanovir, patients taking Abbott's competitors' boosted PI therapies are required to purchase Norvir. Abbott, however, provides ritanovir to patients taking Kaletra at a significantly cheaper price.
Furthermore, as noted in the Court's prior ruling, Plaintiffs offer evidence— comments by Abbott's executives— that suggests Abbott engaged in this conduct with anticompetitive malice. Plaintiffs' experts show that Kaletra sales benefitted from the increase in Norvir's price. Finally, GSK points to damages it suffered based on Abbott's conduct.
Accordingly, Plaintiffs offer sufficient evidence to create a genuine issue of fact with respect to whether Abbott's conduct constituted a violation of its antitrust duty to deal, as defined by Aspen Skiing. Thus, Plaintiffs' monopolization and attempted monopolization claims are viable to the extent that they are based on this theory, as well as on the predatory pricing theory explained above.
Plaintiffs' third theory is that Abbott leveraged its monopoly in the boosting market, which is regulated by government pricing rules, to maintain or obtain a monopoly in the boosted market. At the hearing on Abbott's motions to dismiss Plaintiffs' amended complaints, the Court called this a "monopoly leveraging plus" theory because, although it rests on allegations of monopoly leveraging, it includes the additional factor of government pricing rules in the boosting market. Although Direct Purchasers adopted this theory at the hearing on Abbott's summary judgment motions, only GSK provided briefing on it.
As explained above, the Ninth Circuit in Doe held that, based on Linkline, monopoly leveraging, on its own, is not proscribed under Section 2. GSK asserts that the
The Court is not persuaded. The Ninth Circuit in Doe addressed a free-standing monopoly leveraging theory in the context of the circumstances in this case and held it to be insufficient to sustain a Section 2 claim. Indeed, GSK acknowledges that, in its amicus brief submitted in the Doe appeal, it raised its arguments concerning the government pricing rules.
Further, in Linkline, the defendant's prices in the upstream, wholesale market were likewise subject to regulation. See 129 S.Ct. at 1115. This did not change the outcome in that case. See 129 S.Ct. at 1124 (Breyer, J., concurring in judgment). GSK cites several cases in which courts opined that regulation in a monopolized market, but not in an adjacent market, could alter the analysis as to whether monopoly leveraging, on its own, is actionable. See, e.g., Alaska Airlines, Inc. v. United Airlines, Inc., 948 F.2d 536, 549 (9th Cir. 1991); Town of Concord, Mass. v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17, 29 (1st Cir.1990). However, these cases were decided before Linkline and Doe.
After Linkline and Doe, a free-standing monopoly leveraging theory of liability is not cognizable in this case. Accordingly, the Court summarily adjudicates that Plaintiffs may not base their monopolization and attempted monopolization claims on a "monopoly leveraging plus" theory.
Plaintiffs' final theory of anticompetitive conduct rests on the Sixth Circuit's decision in Conwood. Although Direct Purchasers adopted this theory at the hearing on Abbott's motions, only GSK provided briefing on it.
In Conwood, the defendant destroyed the plaintiff's store racks and offered false information to retailers about competitors' products. 290 F.3d at 775-79, 783. The Sixth Circuit upheld a jury's finding that the defendant's "pervasive practice of destroying [the plaintiff's advertisements] and reducing the number of [the plaintiff's displays] through exclusive agreements with and misrepresentations to retailers was exclusionary conduct without a sufficient justification. . . ." Id. at 788. GSK asserts that Conwood applies here because Abbott's price hike interfered with its ability to promote Lexiva.
Abbott's challenged acts are not analogous to those of the Conwood defendant. The Conwood court stated, "Business torts will be violative of § 2 only in `rare gross cases.'" 290 F.3d at 784. GSK focuses primarily on Abbott's acts of "announcing and timing a massive price hike to hamper a key competitive product upon its introduction." GSK's Opp'n to Abbott's Supp. Brief 6. GSK does not argue that these acts constituted business torts, nor does it contend that Abbott committed the type of widespread tortious conduct at issue in Conwood.
Accordingly, the Court summarily adjudicates that Abbott cannot suffer Section 2 liability based on Conwood. Thus, Plaintiffs'
As noted above, private plaintiffs seeking damages for federal antitrust violations must demonstrate antitrust injury. Abbott challenges Direct Purchasers', although not GSK's, showing with respect to antitrust injury.
First, Abbott relies on Brooke Group v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 113 S.Ct. 2578, 125 L.Ed.2d 168 (1993), to argue that predatory pricing always benefits consumers because, "until the elimination of competition, purchasers. . . can purchase the goods or services at issue for less than if the defendant were not engaged in predatory pricing." Mot. for Summ. J. on Direct Purchasers' Claims 24. However, Brooke Group concerns single-product predatory pricing, where a defendant's products are sold below cost. Under Cascade's bundled discounting exception to Brooke Group, a bundled product can be found to be predatorily priced if the competitive component of the bundled product is deemed, under the "discount attribution standard," to be sold below cost, even though the bundle as a whole is priced above cost. 515 F.3d at 906. Thus, predatory pricing does not always benefit consumers. Here, there is evidence that Direct Purchasers paid supracompetitive prices for Kaletra, a bundled product. This creates a genuine issue of material fact as to whether Direct Purchasers suffered antitrust injury.
Second, Abbott argues that Direct Purchasers' theory of liability is contradictory. On the one hand, Abbott argues, Direct Purchasers claim that it engaged in predatory pricing. Abbott notes that Direct Purchasers maintain that a Kaletra-based therapy costs less than its rivals' therapies because it predatorily priced a bundle of lopinavir and ritanovir. On the other hand, Abbott asserts, Direct Purchasers claim that it charged monopoly prices for Kaletra. These allegations are not necessarily inconsistent. Although Kaletra costs less than other boosted PI therapies, which are more expensive due to Norvir's allegedly inflated price, a jury could agree with Plaintiffs' experts that Abbott's conduct caused all prices in the boosted market to be higher than they would have been, but for Abbott's pricing conduct. Further, Direct Purchasers posit that Abbott's scheme was intended to operate in two stages: (1) the Norvir price increase functioned to raise the cost of Kaletra's rival therapies, making them unattractive to consumers and (2) once this was achieved, Abbott raised the price of Kaletra to a price higher than what Abbott could have commanded but for the Norvir price increase. Direct Purchasers contend that they were injured by Abbott's subsequent inflation of the price of Kaletra, and their experts corroborate this.
Accordingly, summary judgment is not warranted on Direct Purchasers' claims based on Abbott's argument that they fail to show antitrust injury. Because Plaintiffs create triable issues with respect to every element of their Section 2 claims pertaining to the boosted market, Abbott's motion for summary judgment with respect to these claims must be denied.
Direct Purchasers, but not GSK, bring Section 2 claims for Abbott's alleged unlawful monopolization of the boosting market. They assert that Abbott monopolized this market by stifling innovation through inducing its competitors to "standardize around the use of Norvir for boosting purposes." Direct Purchasers' Opp'n 24. Abbott argues that this monopolization
Direct Purchasers offer no evidence to support their claim. They cite Dr. Noll's report, even though he focused solely on how "Abbott's pricing behavior has created an artificial financial barrier to innovation in boosted PIs." Stockinger Decl., Ex. 50, at 132. Indeed, Dr. Noll stated at his deposition that the price hike increased the "incentive to innovate" in the boosting market. Senator Decl., Ex. A, at 61:7-10. Dr. Singer also offers no support. Like Dr. Noll, he addressed reduced innovation in the boosted market and, to the extent that he discussed the boosting market, he merely assumed that "Plaintiffs can show that Abbott's competitors delayed or deferred developing alternatives to Norvir." Stockinger Decl., Ex. 69, at 39-40. Dr. Singer did not identify any evidence that the price hike actually had this effect.
Direct Purchasers did not respond to Abbott's argument that Norvir was not priced below cost, which is a necessary predicate for predatory pricing with respect to single products. See Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 223, 113 S.Ct. 2578. Further, that Abbott had monopoly power in the boosting market and charged monopoly prices does not violate Section 2. Doe, 571 F.3d at 934.
Accordingly, summary judgment is granted on the Direct Purchasers' claims for monopolization of the boosting market.
GSK asserts that Abbott breached the implied covenant of good faith and fair dealing with respect to their licensing agreement for the co-marketing of Norvir and GSK's PIs, including Lexiva.
"The implied covenant of good faith and fair dealing between parties to a contract embraces a pledge that `neither party shall do anything which will have the effect of destroying or injuring the right of the other party to receive the fruits of the contract.'" Moran v. Erk, 11 N.Y.3d 452, 456, 872 N.Y.S.2d 696, 901 N.E.2d 187 (2008) (quoting 511 W. 232nd Owners Corp. v. Jennifer Realty Co., 98 N.Y.2d 144, 153, 746 N.Y.S.2d 131, 773 N.E.2d 496 (2002)). The implied covenant encompasses "`any promises which a reasonable person in the position of the promisee would be justified in understanding were included."' Jennifer Realty, 98 N.Y.2d at 153, 746 N.Y.S.2d 131, 773 N.E.2d 496 (quoting Rowe v. Great Atl. & Pac. Tea Co., 46 N.Y.2d 62, 69, 412 N.Y.S.2d 827, 385 N.E.2d 566 (1978)); accord M/A-COM Sec.Corp. v. Galesi, 904 F.2d 134, 136 (2d Cir.1990) (stating that the implied covenant doctrine is used to "effectuate the intentions of the parties, or to protect their reasonable expectations") (citation omitted).
GSK maintains that Abbott violated the implied covenant by injuring GSK's "right to enhance its profits from Lexiva sales by promoting Lexiva for boosted use with Norvir." GSK Opp'n 7. It maintains that "the purpose of the contract was to allow GSK to increase sales of Lexiva by promoting it with Norvir." Id. In support
Abbott's arguments are unavailing. Although Abbott disputes the nature of the implied promises arising from its agreement with GSK, this is not sufficient to justify summary judgment. The evidence supports a finding that, after executing a co-marketing agreement with Abbott, GSK justifiably understood that Abbott would not drastically increase the price of Norvir at a time designed to interfere with the launch of GSK's co-marketed product. Abbott also argues that there is no evidence that it "`directly destroyed'" GSK's right to co-promote its products with Norvir. Reply at 11 (quoting M/A-COM, 904 F.2d at 136). However, GSK's theory is that Abbott injured, not destroyed, its right.
Abbott also cites Moran, in which New York's high court rejected the plaintiffs' claim for a breach of the implied covenant. There, the plaintiffs claimed that they were deprived of "the fruits" of a contract when the defendants, after having "qualms about purchasing the Morans' house," instructed their attorney not to approve the purchase contract. 11 N.Y.3d at 454-55, 872 N.Y.S.2d 696, 901 N.E.2d 187. The court, however, noted that the contract contained a clause that explicitly stated that the contract was "contingent upon approval by attorneys for Seller and Purchaser." Id. at 456, 872 N.Y.S.2d 696, 901 N.E.2d 187 (emphasis omitted). Based on this clause, the court concluded that "the plain language of the contract in this case makes clear that any `fruits' of the contract were contingent on attorney approval, as any reasonable person in the Morans' position should have understood." Id. at 457, 872 N.Y.S.2d 696, 901 N.E.2d 187. Here, there were no contingencies placed on GSK's right to co-market its PIs with Norvir. Indeed, Tyree testified that, at the time of their negotiations, Abbott did not inform GSK that it was then considering changes in either the supply or price of Norvir.
Abbott does not establish that, as a matter of law, it was unreasonable for GSK to expect that Abbott would not injure its right to market its PIs along with Norvir.
GSK seeks damages for the breach of the implied covenant in the form of its alleged lost profits, and restitution for the consideration it offered for the co-marketing license.
Abbott maintains that, under New York law, lost profits are consequential damages that are not recoverable for a breach of the implied covenant. Abbott also argues that, because lost profits are consequential damages, a liability-limiting clause in the contract bars GSK from recovering them.
In Tractebel Energy Marketing, Inc. v. AEP Power Marketing, Inc., the Second Circuit, applying New York law, explained the difference between lost profits as consequential damages and as general damages:
487 F.3d 89, 109-10 (2d Cir.2007) (footnotes, citations and internal quotation marks omitted); see also Am. List Corp. v. U.S. News & World Report, Inc., 75 N.Y.2d 38, 43, 550 N.Y.S.2d 590, 549 N.E.2d 1161 (1989).
Here, GSK maintains that it would have received additional revenue from third parties had Abbott not raised the price of Norvir. See GSK Opp'n 11. GSK does not contend that any of its lost profits are monies owed by Abbott under the contract. Thus, the lost profits GSK seeks are best characterized as consequential, not general, damages.
Abbott cites Travellers International A.G. v. TWA, 41 F.3d 1570 (2d Cir.1994), for the proposition that New York law precludes recovery of consequential damages for breach of the implied covenant. There, the Second Circuit stated that "a damage award for lost profits cannot rest upon the breach of the implied duty of good faith and fair dealing." Id. at 1576. However, the court did not cite any authority for this proposition, and Abbott did not identify, nor did the Court find, any supporting New York case law. The Travellers court affirmed the award of lost profits as damages, although based on the theory that the defendant breached a provision of the contract. 41 F.3d at 1577-81. Further, contrary to the Second Circuit's statement, a New York state appellate court found cognizable a request for consequential damages based on a breach of the implied covenant, concluding that the request was sufficiently plead. Panasia Estates, Inc. v. Hudson Ins. Co., 68 A.D.3d 530, 889 N.Y.S.2d 452, 453 (2009). Because there is no authority that bars recovery for lost profits based on a breach of the implied covenant, summary judgment is not warranted on this ground.
Abbott next argues that the parties' contract prohibits recovery for consequential damages. The relevant provision states, "EXCEPT AS OTHERWISE PROVIDED, NEITHER PARTY SHALL BE LIABLE FOR ANY SPECIAL, INCIDENTAL, INDIRECT OR CONSEQUENTIAL LOSSES ARISING OUT OF OR RELATING TO THIS AGREEMENT. . . ." Calamari Decl., Ex. 23 at NOR00004428 (upper case in original). Abbott's conduct, however, could render the relevant provision inoperable.
In Sommer v. Federal Signal Corporation, New York's high court stated that it "is the public policy of this State . . . that a party may not insulate itself from damages caused by grossly negligent conduct," a principle that "applies equally to contract clauses purporting to exonerate a party from liability and clauses limiting damages to a nominal sum." 79 N.Y.2d 540, 554, 583 N.Y.S.2d 957, 593 N.E.2d 1365 (1992). The court explained that, to render such a clause inoperative, conduct must evince "a reckless indifference to the rights of others" and "smack of intentional wrongdoing." Id. (citations and editing and quotation marks omitted).
In a subsequent case, Metropolitan Life Insurance Company v. Noble Lowndes International,
Id. at 438, 618 N.Y.S.2d 882, 643 N.E.2d 504.
Here, there is sufficient evidence to support an inference that Abbott's action smacked of intentional wrongdoing. Internal documents suggest that Abbott intended to injure GSK's right to co-market Lexiva with Norvir. Further, several documents suggest that Abbott intended to recapture and maintain Kaletra's market share, at the expense of Lexiva and other boosted PIs. GSK presents evidence that, while Abbott was negotiating with it regarding the terms of the license, it was concurrently investigating methods by which it could diminish the license's value. Abbott never informed GSK that it was considering withdrawing or raising dramatically the price of Norvir, two material facts that Abbott knew would have altered the nature of the negotiations. See Stockinger Decl., Ex. 1 at 134:22-24 (Tyree stated that it is "inconsistent to think about withdrawing a product that we're actually issuing licenses on"). Abbott announced the price hike on December 3, 2003, apparently adopting a staff recommendation to implement the increase at the same time as GSK's late-November launch of Lexiva. Abbott adopted this timing as a "clever creative way to make them look bad." Stockinger Decl., Ex. 21 at RIT0437394. Finally, the price hike caused the cost of GSK's Lexiva-based therapy to jump approximately seventy-one percent. This evidence, and the reasonable inferences that can be drawn from it, create a triable issue as to whether Abbott meets the standard set in Sommer.
Accordingly, GSK may recover lost profit damages based on Abbott's conduct, if it proves that Abbott acted with reckless indifference to its right to co-market its products with Norvir.
Abbott contends that one form of consideration for which GSK seeks restitution on its breach of the implied covenant claim was the subject of a separate contract and, as a result, cannot be recovered for a breach of the covenant with respect to the Norvir license.
Abbott seeks summary judgment on GSK's claim for violation of North Carolina's UDTPA to the extent that it is based on GSK's allegations that Abbott breached the implied covenant of good faith and fair dealing and deceived consumers through statements it made regarding the Norvir price increase. Abbott does not seek summary judgment on GSK's claim for monopolization or attempted monopolization of "any part of trade or commerce in the State of North Carolina," in violation of the UDTPA. N.C. Gen.Stat. § 75-2.1.
To prove a violation of the UDTPA, a plaintiff must show: "(1) an unfair or deceptive act or practice, or unfair method of competition, (2) in or affecting commerce, and (3) which proximately caused actual injury to the plaintiff or his business." Miller v. Nationwide Mut. Ins. Co., 112 N.C. App. 295, 301, 435 S.E.2d 537 (1993).
"The question of what constitutes an unfair or deceptive trade practice is an issue of law." Nelson v. Hartford Underwriters Ins. Co., 177 N.C. App. 595, 609, 630 S.E.2d 221 (2006). "A practice is unfair when it offends established public policy as well as when the practice is immoral, unethical, oppressive, unscrupulous, or substantially injurious to consumers." Marshall v. Miller, 302 N.C. 539, 548, 276 S.E.2d 397 (1981). "Stated another way, a party is guilty of an unfair act or practice when it engages in conduct which amounts to an inequitable assertion of its power or position." Carcano v. JBSS, LLC, 684 S.E.2d 41, 50 (N.C.App.2009) (citation and internal quotation marks omitted). When determining whether an act violates the UDTPA, courts must consider "the effect of the actor's conduct on the consuming public." Marshall, 302 N.C. at 548, 276 S.E.2d 397.
"A simple breach of contract, even if intentional, does not amount to a violation of the Act; a plaintiff must show substantial aggravating circumstances attending the breach to recover under the Act, which allows for treble damages." Bartolomeo v. S.B. Thomas, Inc., 889 F.2d 530, 535 (4th Cir.1989); accord Bob Timberlake Collection, Inc. v. Edwards, 176 N.C. App. 33, 42, 626 S.E.2d 315 (2006).
The evidence supporting an award of consequential damages for GSK's breach of the implied covenant claim under New York law could also support liability under the UDTPA based on Abbott's alleged breach. As noted above, the price hike caused the cost of a Lexiva-based therapy to increase seventy-one percent overnight. There is evidence to suggest that this increase was specifically intended to interfere with GSK's launch of Lexiva. Further, the price hike resulted in a sudden and substantial increase in the cost to HIV patients in need of treatment.
There are few guides regarding what constitutes sufficiently egregious conduct
Here, although there is no indication that Abbott did not intend to fulfill the explicit terms of the license, there is evidence that Abbott knew that it was taking steps that would undermine the license's value. If the evidence is construed as described above, Abbott's conduct could be found "unethical, oppressive, unscrupulous" and "substantially injurious to consumers." Thus, summary judgment is not warranted on GSK's UDTPA claim to the extent it is based on Abbott's alleged breach of the implied covenant of good faith and fair dealing.
Summary judgment, however, is warranted on GSK's UDPTA claim to the extent it is based on Abbott's allegedly deceptive representations to the public about the Norvir price increase. Although Abbott's statements to the public may have been deceptive, GSK does not offer any evidence that it suffered proximate injury from them.
Accordingly, the Court summarily adjudicates that GSK cannot base its UDTPA claim on Abbott's alleged deception of consumers. In all other respects, Abbott's motion concerning GSK's UDTPA claim is denied.
For the foregoing reasons, Abbott's motions for summary judgment on the Direct Purchasers' claims (C 07-5470 CW, Docket No. 232; C 07-5985 CW, Docket No. 332; C 07-6120 CW, Docket No. 213; C 07-5702 CW, Docket No. 287) and GSK's claims (C 07-5470 CW, Docket No. 227; C 07-5985, Docket No. 328; C 07-6120 CW, Docket No. 209; C 07-5702 CW, Docket No. 283) are GRANTED in part and DENIED in part. The Court makes the following rulings:
A final pretrial conference is scheduled for February 8, 2011 at 2:00 p.m. A fifteen-day jury trial is set to begin on February 28, 2011 at 8:30 a.m.
IT IS SO ORDERED.